Μετάβαση στο κύριο περιεχόμενο

Similarities between Irish famine and Greek austerity should worry us

Is there an alternative to the 'sharp but effectual remedy'?

Are the shipments of grain that left Ireland during its 19th-century famine that different from the flows of money now leaving Greece and elsewhere to pay the interest on government debt, asks Oxford economics professor Simon Wren-Lewis

Between 1846 and 1851 about a million died of starvation and epidemic disease in the Irish potato famine. The general consensus today is that although this famine began as an extraordinary natural catastrophe, its impact was made much worse by the actions (or lack of action) of the British government, headed by the Whig Lord John Russell.
As Jim Donnelly describes, there seem to be three ideologies that held the "British political élite and the middle classes in their grip, and largely determined the decisions not to adopt the possible relief measures". These were "the economic doctrines of laissez-faire, the Protestant evangelical belief in divine Providence, and the deep-dyed ethnic prejudice against the Catholic Irish".
The system of agriculture in Ireland was perceived in Britain to be riddled with inefficiency and abuse. The British civil servant Charles Trevelyan, chiefly responsible for administering Irish relief policy, wrote that the famine was "the sharp but effectual remedy by which the cure is likely to be effected".
There is a debate about the humanity and personal responsibility of Charles Trevelyan. Yet his actions were hardly idiosyncratic. The Lord Lieutenant of Ireland, the Earl of Clarendon, wrote a letter to prime minister Russell on 26 April 1849, expressing his feelings about lack of aid from the British House of Commons: "I do not think there is another legislature in Europe that would disregard such suffering as now exists in the west of Ireland, or coldly persist in a policy of extermination."
Henry Farrell notes that the Economist magazine strongly supported the laissez-faire line pursued by Trevelyan and Russell. Were the governing elite collectively evil, as they provided armed guards for the shipping of huge quantities of grain away from the same areas affected by the blight? We could just say people act in their own interests, but as Dani Rodrik argues, this underestimates the power of ideas and ideologies.
Of course the Irish famine is different in degree and form to the difficulties being faced by many in some eurozone economies. But the similarities should worry us. There is the widespread view that the inefficiencies and corruption that exist in these economies are a key factor in explaining the difficulties these countries are in. Worse still is the idea that severe austerity is necessary to ensure "structural reform" takes place to reduce these inefficiencies. There is also a common belief today that various economic processes cannot be interfered with and contracts have to be upheld, which are not very different from beliefs held by the British government in the 1840s. When the "effectual remedy" leads directly to suffering, the evidence that it does so is ignored, as a recentLancet paper, entitled "Greece's health crisis: from austerity to denialism", is happening in Greece today.
It finds that "drastic reductions to municipality budgets have led to a scaling back of several activities (eg, mosquito spraying programmes), which, in combination with other factors, has allowed the re-emergence of locally transmitted malaria for the first time in 40 years." It also mentions "a 21% rise in stillbirths between 2008 and 2011 … attributed to reduced access to prenatal health services for pregnant women."
By denialism, the authors mean the following:
Greek citizens ... are subject to one of the most radical programmes of welfare-state retrenchment in recent times, which in turn affects population health. Yet despite this clear evidence, there has been little agreement about the causal role of austerity. There is a broad consensus that the social sector in Greece was in grave need of reform, with widespread corruption, misuse of patronage, and inefficiencies, and many commentators have noted that the crisis presented an opportunity to introduce long-overdue changes. Greek government officials, and several sympathetic commentators, have argued that the introduction of the wide ranging changes and deep public-spending cuts have not damaged health and, indeed, might lead to long-term improvements. However, the scientific literature presents a different picture. In view of this detailed body of evidence for the harmful effects of austerity on health, the failure of public recognition of the issue by successive Greek governments and international agencies is remarkable.
If you think that the problems in Greece and elsewhere are clearly self-inflicted, rather than the result of an act of God-like potato blight, consider this. The Greek government borrowed way too much and concealed that fact, but this was hidden from the Greek people as much as anyone else. Just because politicians are elected, does that make the people as a whole responsible for everything they do? Are they more responsible than those who lent the government this money, or in the case of other eurozone countries lent money to banks that were subsequently bailed out with no public discussion?
In Victorian times, there was a belief that the debtor must be made to repay their debts whatever the hardship that this entails, and with minimal cost to the creditor. We think we live in more enlightened times today, but at least the individuals in debtor prisons normally signed the contracts they were being held to. In the case of Greece and elsewhere their leaders signed on their population’s behalf.
If you say that the law must be followed, well the British government was also protecting the rule of law when it ensured that those shipments of grain left famine-stricken Ireland. Are those shipments of grain so very different from the flows of money now leaving Greece and elsewhere to pay the interest on government debt? Our attitude to famines is a little more enlightened than it was in the 1840s, but perhaps some of that enlightenment is needed elsewhere.
Simon Wren-Lewis is a professor of economics at Merton College, Oxford University. This is a slightly edited version of a post that originally appeared on his Mainly Macro blog

Δημοφιλείς αναρτήσεις από αυτό το ιστολόγιο

Οι Σαϊτάρχες, ο Γαβράς και τα ανεβαστήρια

Ενας ελαφρύς κυματισμός παρατηρήθηκε στον απέραντο βάλτο της ελληνικής "ενημέρωσης" με την "γκάφα" της "είδησης" για το "θάνατο" του Κώστα Γαβρά, στις 30 Αυγούστου.
Η ιστορία λίγο πολύ γνωστή. Ενας ιταλός δάσκαλος-δημοσιογράφος υποδυόμενος  στο Twitter την ελληνίδα υπουργό Πολιτισμού "ανακοινώνει" το θάνατο του σκηνοθέτη. Μεγάλα ξένα Μέσα και σχεδόν ΟΛΑ τα ελληνικά αναμεταδίδουν το ψεύτικο tweet και θρηνούν για τον "μακαρίτη". Η απάτη αποκαλύπτεται σχεδόν αμέσως από ένα αμερικανικό site και σχεδόν ταυτόχρονα από την ΕΡΤ δημοσιογράφοι της οποίας επικοινωνούν με το Γαβρά. Την ίδια στιγμή τα όρνεα των ιδιωτικών τηλεοράσεων εξαπολύουν επιθέσεις κατά της υπουργού Πολιτισμού καλώντας την να παραιτηθεί.
Το θέμα παίρνει διαστάσεις καθώς οι χρήστες των κοινωνικών δικτύων κονιορτοποιούν για μία ακόμη φορά την ούτως ή άλλως μηδαμινή αξιοπιστία των ελληνικών ΜΜΕ και των "λειτουργών" τους.
Κάποιοι, οι πιο ρομαντικοί, απαιτούν μ…

Ολα τα Μνημόνια σε πίνακες

Της Ελενας Κάππα


Σήμερα η εφημερίδα Αυγή δημοσιεύει έναν συγκριτικό πίνακα των τριών Μνημονίων, ο οποίος ενόψει της προεκλογικής περιόδου είναι βέβαιο ότι θα αποβεί εξαιρετικά χρήσιμος. Ο πίνακας περιλαμβάνει το συνολικό ύψος των πρόσθετων μέτρων κατά τη διάρκεια της συμφωνηθείσας περιόδου, το ύψος των μέτρων κατανεμημένο σε ετήσια βάση, το ύψος των πρωτογενών πλεονασμάτων, τη προσαρμογή του ετήσιου κόστους των μέτρων λόγω ελάφρυνσης των πρωτογενών πλεονασμάτων, την εξοικονόμηση του κόστους λόγω και αναδιάρθρωσης  χρέους την τριετία 2016-2018 και τέλος τη προσαρμογή του ετήσιου κόστους λόγω και αναδιάρθρωσης του χρέους. Μνημόνιο 1 Το συνολικό ύψος των πρόσθετων μέτρων στη διάρκεια 2,4 ετών (2010-2012) ανήλθε σε 40,6 δις ενώ το ύψος των μέτρων σε ετήσια βάση έφτασε τα 16,9 δις. Κατά τη διάρκεια του πρώτου μνημονίου δεν υπήρξε συμφωνία σε σχέση με τα πρωτογενή πλεονάσματα που θα έπρεπε να πετύχει η ελληνική κυβέρνηση, ούτε κάποια δέσμευση για αναδιάρθρωση χρέους. Μνημόνιο 2 Κατά το δεύ…

Ω! Τα Ωραία Μικρά Μαγαζιά του 3%

Ω! Οι ωραίες μέρες!
Νοσταλγώ τις ένδοξες στιγμές μας στην Αριστερά του ’80 και του ’90 και του 2000 και του 2007…
Μικρά μαγαζιά, γωνία. Σπίτια του λαού. Ωραία κυλικεία με εξαιρετικούς καφέδες το πρωί.
Ωραίες μέρες…
Στα Ντα Κάπο και στα Φίλια, θέσεις τιμητικές μαζί με καλλιτέχνες και ωραία κορίτσια και αγόρια. Σεβασμός για την εργατική τραγιάσκα που είχαμε από καιρό πάψει να φοράμε αλλά ειχε μείνει η γραμμή στο μέτωπο. Ηθική. Συνέπεια. Καθαρότητα. Αγαπητοί σε όλους. Ευχάριστοι.
Αποδεκτοι όσο δεν διεκδικούσαμε κάτι παραπάνω. Την εξουσία κυρίως… «Αυτά δεν είναι δουλειές για εσάς. Θα σας φθείρουν! Αφήστε τις για εμάς τους λερωμένους…» μας έλεγαν οι πράσινοι και γαλάζιοι φίλοι μας. Και τα κορίτσια το ίδιο μας έλεγαν.
Εκεί στο 3 με 8% ήμασταν μια χαρά όλοι. Κι εμείς και οι άλλοι. Ασφαλείς μέσα στις αναζητήσεις μας. Χωρίς να το πιέζουμε κιόλας.
Και χρήσιμοι! Πολύ χρήσιμοι για πολλούς λόγους. Κυρίως για άλλοθι βέβαια αλλά και λόγω παιδείας. Ως δημοσιογράφοι. Ως Σύμβουλοι. Ως Ρήτορες.
Τι έλεγα;
Α! Ναι…